Eisspeedway

Talk:Approval voting: Difference between revisions

Content deleted Content added
Syd1435 (talk | contribs)
Kowey (talk | contribs)
Line 140: Line 140:


<div style="background-color:#ffdddd;">
<div style="background-color:#ffdddd;">
: I think it is a mistaken assumption that accounting for (proportional) preferences between candidates is even neccesary or desirable, but that's just my opinion. Seems like the most important thing in an election is to prevent tactical voting, and allow voters to vote sincerely for who they want without having to perform any calculations. That being said, I think the article already mentions that AppV does not account for preferences, but IRV does, but then again, IRV has its fair share of problems, in that attempting to account for preferences, it also introduces some potential for strategic voting, no? -- [[User:Kowey|Kowey]] 09:26, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
: I think it is a mistaken assumption that accounting for (proportional) preferences between candidates is even neccesary or desirable, but that's just my opinion. Seems like the most important thing in an election is to prevent tactical voting, and allow voters to vote sincerely for who they want without having to perform any calculations. That being said, I think the article already mentions that AppV does not account for preferences, but IRV does, but then again, IRV has its fair share of problems, in that attempting to account for preferences, it also introduces some potential for <s>strategic</s> tactical voting, no? -- [[User:Kowey|Kowey]] 09:26, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
</div>


:: I assume that tactical and strategic voting are the same thing, choosing a lesser choice, to avoid a worst choice. IRV is the one system that avoids the need for any of this negative tactical voting. You rank all the candidates, and the full value of that vote stays still or shifts until either it is victorious or is defeated.
<div style="background-color:#ffdddd;">
:::: I assume that tactical and strategic voting are the same thing, choosing a lesser choice, to avoid a worst choice. IRV is the one system that avoids the need for any of this negative tactical voting. You rank all the candidates, and the full value of that vote stays still or shifts until either it is victorious or is defeated.


As is being shown in the 9 Oct 2004 election, if there are a lot of candidates competing for a seat, the flow of preferences are too complicated for mere onlookers (and even the candidates themselves) to really know what is going on, but all will be revealled as the Electoral Commission crunches its numbers.
::As is being shown in the 9 Oct 2004 election, if there are a lot of candidates competing for a seat, the flow of preferences are too complicated for mere onlookers (and even the candidates themselves) to really know what is going on, but all will be revealled as the Electoral Commission crunches its numbers.


PS how do I change the background colours?
::PS how do I change the background colours?


[[User:Syd1435|Syd1435]] 12:24, 2004 Oct 16 (UTC)
::[[User:Syd1435|Syd1435]] 12:24, 2004 Oct 16 (UTC)

:::I am using tactical/strategic voting interchangably. If there is any difference, somebody shout. For now, i'll try to use "tactical voting" strategically.

:::Anyway, I'm not trying to dodge the discussion here, but we need to keep in mind that the goal is <em>not</em> to determine which is the superior voting system, but to present the user with descriptions of them, as well as a fair discussion on their relative strengths/weaknesses. Yes it's tough to draw the line between such a discussion and the one we are having now, but we should be making a stronger effort to avoid steering the user to any conclusions which are based on opinion or ideals.

:::Also, No need to change background colours and/or create new div tags. My only goal was to set our discussion aside from your original text.
:::-- [[User:Kowey|Kowey]] 13:13, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
</div>
</div>


Line 176: Line 181:


:::I think your orders of magnitude come from a poor choice of algorithm. The number of ballots in IRV is irrelvant; you only need to store M^2 numbers: for each candidate, the number of 1st rank votes, 2nd rank votes, etc. In other words, IRV is simpler to implement than you suggest, so be happy, but all this talk of complexity is not relevant to article on voting systems. -- [[User:Kowey|Kowey]] 11:20, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
:::I think your orders of magnitude come from a poor choice of algorithm. The number of ballots in IRV is irrelvant; you only need to store M^2 numbers: for each candidate, the number of 1st rank votes, 2nd rank votes, etc. In other words, IRV is simpler to implement than you suggest, so be happy, but all this talk of complexity is not relevant to article on voting systems. -- [[User:Kowey|Kowey]] 11:20, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
</div>


<div style="background-color:#fadada;">
:::: I am trying to concede that IRV requires more resources than other systems, and if these resources are not available, then a system like AppV would be a satisfactory second preference. If you are not bothered, fine. :-)
:::: I am trying to concede that IRV requires more resources than other systems, and if these resources are not available, then a system like AppV would be a satisfactory second preference. If you are not bothered, fine. :-)


:::: BTW, information must be stored for each of the N ballots, because with IRV, unlike FPTP or AppV, you cannot just add up the numbers on the ballot papers as they go by. These ballots must be reprocessed as many as M-1 times to attain a result.
:::: BTW, information must be stored for each of the N ballots, because with IRV, unlike FPTP or AppV, you cannot just add up the numbers on the ballot papers as they go by. These ballots must be reprocessed as many as M-1 times to attain a result.


::::: Fine, my mistake; i hadn't understood how the IRV transfer worked and after rereading carefully, I will tentatively agree that you will need to store each ballot. But no, I am not bothered, and concession is not neccesary because I think it's not really pertinent to the article. -- [[User:Kowey|Kowey]] 13:13, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
</div>
</div>



Revision as of 13:13, 16 October 2004

It is easily reversed as disapproval voting where a choice is disavowed, as is already required in other measures in politics (e.g. representative recall).

I don't see why approval voting is any different than any other system for "disapproval". The case cited (representative recall) is not even a single-winner contest. (throw all the bums out :-). It is a single-candidate contest if anything.... I propose dropping that text. NealMcB 18:10, 2004 Apr 29 (UTC)


Reads well now. The point about approval and preference voting both being single-vote systems is now there, but no hierarchy of 'this is a type of that' is anywhere in the descriptions of the voting systems themselves, which is fine, except for disapproval as a variant of approval, which seems the only clear inverse. 15:02, 2003 Jan 17

There was an earlier article here once, but it must have been censored.


Under Approval_voting#Potential_for_Tactical_voting I don't like this statement:

A good strategy is to vote for every candidate the voter prefers to the leading candidate, and to also vote for the leading candidate if he is preferred to the current second-place candidate. When all voters follow this strategy, the Condorcet winner is almost certain to win.

It is an opinion statement and I don't know what qualifications should be made for it. Who says this is a good strategy? How do we measure the "leading candidate"? Is that an approval measure or a plurality measure?!

I've done my own thoughts on Approval Voting and I judge:

A good strategy is to vote for the same candidate you would vote for in a plurality race, and also any candidates you prefer more (ignoring any assumption that those candidates can't win).

This stategy is more practical, and is MUCH more likely to be used, even if it doesn't help the Condorcet Winner.

It would merely allow weak candidates a fair measure of support (approval) without throwing the election against a preferred stronger candidate. Approval offers little to voters in a strong three-way race when the top leader is not predictable. Then approval is only useful as a maximal power "negative vote" against feared competitor(s). (Voting A=1,B=1,C=0 in approval is mathematically equivalent to A=0,B=0,C=-1)

I won't change anything for now, but I appreciate opinions. I accept the existing "good strategy" statement as "Good strategy to elect a Condorcet Winner".

Does anyone else have a problem with the existing "good strategy" statement? Any suggestions for changes?

Thanks! --Tomruen 00:02, 2 Jun 2004 (UTC)

The problem with your phrase is that the vote in a tactical vote in a plurality race may also depend on identifying the leading candidates in a plurality race, the leading candidates may be different under different rules and the information may not be avialable on how others might vote in a plurality race. For those who wish to vote in a way which is unlikely to affect the result, tactical voting advice is unnecessary, and I think the current text makes reasonable sense - the leading candidate obviously means in an approval measure. --Henrygb 23:16, 26 Jun 2004 (UTC)
Hmmm... my first assumption was "leading candidate" meant leading in a single-vote count since it is pretty much meaningless to poll voters with approval votes in a poll. Approval polling is too strongly open to manipulation, even unorganized manipulation - individuals playing around for fun or profit. I accept the same argument exists with single-vote counts, but people still want their true favorite to poll well and are less likely to play unless they really have no preference. --Tom Ruen 05:37, Jun 27, 2004 (UTC)

My question is why approval voting is single winner only. Is it called something else when the top n candidates are elected? --Henrygb 23:16, 26 Jun 2004 (UTC)

Approval certainly could be used for multiwinner elections and doesn't have or need any different name. In practice there's less reason to need it. The "standard" multiwinner election method is called Plurality-at-large or Bloc-voting which allows as many votes as candidates. It's less often people would want to "overvote" with multiple winners except as a defensive vote against one or more most disliked candidates. A more likely vote in plurality-at-large is voting for less candidates than winners because you don't want your lower choices to defeat higher ones.
Actually multiwinner Approval elections are an attractive idea - but only when candidates are truly evaluated independently - that is if the number of winners can be variable and the approval rating needed is fixed before the election.
For example a great application would be a poll for which ALL candidates with more than 15% approval are included in a presidential debate. That's a very valid poll since you know the more you vote for the more winners there will be and your vote for a second favorite CAN'T hurt the chances of winning for a first favorite. --Tom Ruen 05:37, Jun 27, 2004 (UTC)

Approval Voting and the Florida 2000 Butterfly Ballot.

Some thoughts:

  • If Approval Voting had been in force in Florida 2000, then the mistakenly double marked ballots (for Gore and Buchanan) would still have counted. No votes would have been voided. Gore would have got all his genuine votes, while Buchanan was so far behind it would not have mattered it he got some bonus or unintended approval votes.
  • Does Approval Voting comply with "one man one vote"? Yes it does, because any Buchanan votes do not really matter because he was so far behind, and Gore only ever recieves "one useful vote per voter".
  • Has Approval Voting ever actually been used anywhere?
  • The biggest disadvantage of Approval Voting may be that it distorts the election statistics - the total number of votes may appear to add up to more than 100%. Something would need to be done to "normalise" the results.
  • If the votes in an Approval Vote contest add up to more than 100% turnout, how does convince the public that the election has not be tampered with? That might be a hard sell!
  • If 999 Nader voters had approved of Gore, Gore would have beaten Bush.
  • If 999 Buchanan voters had also approved of Bush, Bush would still have won.
  • Note that there were 3rd Party candidates spoiling things on both sides.

Syd1435 09:23, 2004 Oct 4 (UTC)

The dilemma with Approval Voting

Suppose one side of politics is a permanent Coalition, say City Republicans and Rural Republicans, and an election is being held using Approval Voting.

  • If you do not mind which kind of Republican gets in, you approve of both kinds.
  • But say for some reason or another, you would much prefer the Rural Republican to get elected - how then do you fill in your Ballot?
  • Answer, you must approve of the RR candidate and disapprove of the CR candidate.
  • Suppose there are other voters who prefer the City Republican candidate.
  • Taken together, the two Republican candidates will lose a few votes compared to the sole Democratic candidate.
  • There is thus a dangerous split in the Republican camp, albeit a modest one.
  • This illustrates a flaw in Approval Voting, because all approvals have the same value, when in practice, some variation in the approval rating is desirable.

What is needed is some kind of intermediate approval level. Here is a sample ballot paper, to enable both Republicans to be approved, but with one preferred to the other. Then all Republican votes count toward beating the common enemy.


  • [3] Joe Smith ----- Greens.
  • [1] Henry Ford ---- Rural Republican
  • [3] Jane Doe ------ Democrat
  • [3] Fred Rubble --- Reform
  • [2] Mary Hill ----- City Republican

Notes:

  • [1] = 1st preference Approval (YES-FULL)
  • [2] = 2nd preference Approval (YES-PART)
  • [3] = Disapproval............ (NO)

Note that the Modified Approval Voting with variable levels of preference is starting to look like Instant Runoff Voting.

Put this the other way, Approval Voting is a restictive version of Instant Runoff Voting where instead of having N different ranks for N candidates, you are restricted to 2 different ranks for N candidates.

selling IRV

Hi Syd1435,

I'm moving your discussion of Approval voting's flaws to the talk page for two reasons (1) because it really looks like you're actively trying to plug IRV [instead of dispassionately describing the flaws in AppV] (2) the tone of the content is really a lot more conversational than it is encyclopedic. Let's work together to bring the most useful content from your contributions back to the article. Best, -- Kowey 08:55, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)

P.S. I will confess that I am partial to AppV myself, so we should also get help from a more neutral 3rd party.

Since AV is also an abbreviation for Alternate Vote aka IRV, can we abbreviate Approval Voting as AppV?

I think it helps to compare FPTP, AppV and AltV aka IRV rather than dealt with them dispassionately on their own.

BTW, the 9 Oct Election is very exciting because preferential voting (IRV), slow absentee and postal ballots, mean that unexpected and interesting results are occurring. No point in having it all over on election night.

I am happy to work with you to get something acceptable back of article page.

Syd1435 12:10, 2004 Oct 16 (UTC)


One Man One Vote

  • In an Approval Vote election, the total number of approvals will add up to more than 100% of the number of voters, which may appear to some people as a breech of the "One Man One Vote" principle. It is not a breech, but how does one argue that it is not a breech?

(note: using a different colour to set discussion apart from content)

One man one vote means that nobody has more voting rights than anybody else. Seems perfectly intact: everybody has the same ability to choose as many candidates as he wants. Another way to look at this issue is to think of "not voting for" a candidate as equivalent to "voting against" that candidate. In other words, everybody gets one vote on each candidate: yes or no. In any case, this needs to be massaged into encyclopedic form or left out -- Kowey 09:26, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
I agree that FPTP, AppV and IRV are all "One man one vote meaning that nobody has more voting rights than anybody else." However, during the Alaskan referendum for IRV, the AK League of Women Voters (though not the national LWV) questioned whether IRV was compatible with one man one vote. They got no satisfactory answer, and so opposed any change. This was very disappointing. The AK LWV thought that if your preferences were transferred N times, that was one man N votes for some, while only 1 man 1 vote for others. A better answer to the AK LWV might be to say that no matter how many times preferences are transferred, the total number of votes remains constant, thus one man one vote.
Syd1435 10:45, 2004 Oct 16 (UTC)


  • Suppose that a voter approves of candidates B and C; but approves of candidate B more than C. How does he cast his votes?
    • If he approves of only B, the lack of an approval vote for C may let A in.
    • If he approves of both B and C, then he has failed to express his preference for B over C.
    • It is thus impossible to simultaneously approve of two candidates which preferring one over the other.
    • Approval voting suffers the disadvantage that all approvals are of equal weight, even when the vote wishes to express unequal approvals.
I think it is a mistaken assumption that accounting for (proportional) preferences between candidates is even neccesary or desirable, but that's just my opinion. Seems like the most important thing in an election is to prevent tactical voting, and allow voters to vote sincerely for who they want without having to perform any calculations. That being said, I think the article already mentions that AppV does not account for preferences, but IRV does, but then again, IRV has its fair share of problems, in that attempting to account for preferences, it also introduces some potential for strategic tactical voting, no? -- Kowey 09:26, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
I assume that tactical and strategic voting are the same thing, choosing a lesser choice, to avoid a worst choice. IRV is the one system that avoids the need for any of this negative tactical voting. You rank all the candidates, and the full value of that vote stays still or shifts until either it is victorious or is defeated.
As is being shown in the 9 Oct 2004 election, if there are a lot of candidates competing for a seat, the flow of preferences are too complicated for mere onlookers (and even the candidates themselves) to really know what is going on, but all will be revealled as the Electoral Commission crunches its numbers.
PS how do I change the background colours?
Syd1435 12:24, 2004 Oct 16 (UTC)
I am using tactical/strategic voting interchangably. If there is any difference, somebody shout. For now, i'll try to use "tactical voting" strategically.
Anyway, I'm not trying to dodge the discussion here, but we need to keep in mind that the goal is not to determine which is the superior voting system, but to present the user with descriptions of them, as well as a fair discussion on their relative strengths/weaknesses. Yes it's tough to draw the line between such a discussion and the one we are having now, but we should be making a stronger effort to avoid steering the user to any conclusions which are based on opinion or ideals.
Also, No need to change background colours and/or create new div tags. My only goal was to set our discussion aside from your original text.
-- Kowey 13:13, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
  • These two problems are resolved with Instant Runoff Voting.
    • With IRV, the total number of votes for each candidate at every stage of the count equals the number of votes orignally cast.
    • If a votes put B first, C second and A third, then the full value of his vote is set against B in the first round. Depending on how B and C score against eachother, either the second preferences of C go to B, or the second preferences of B go to C. No votes need be lost in the struggle between like minded B and C against the common enemy A.
    • In military terms, there is no "Division of Force" when a voter preferences B before C. No matter whether a votes remains with its original choice, or is redistributed to a lower choice, that vote always retains its full value, one man, one vote, one value.
  • There is a problem with Instant Runoff Voting that in practice is no longer a problem.
    • With Approval Voting, Limited Voting, and the like, when a computer is used to tally the results, only the total score for each candidate need be recorded. This requires only a small Commodure 64 computer with 64k of memory.
    • With Instant Runoff Voting, it is necessary to store an image of every ballot; it there are N ballots, and M candidates per ballot, then a Pentium computer with N * M bytes or even double bytes of memory is required.
    • It can also be represented with much less memory. Just as the example above represented many voters with just four columns, you can get my with just counting how many ef each *unique* ballot exists. You only need M * (M!) entries, each entry able to count up to N. For M=4 candidates, this comes to 96 entries. For M=10 candidates, this comes to about 36 mega-entries.
    • If Department of Elections only has Commodore 64 computers at its disposal, then a computerised IRV may be out of the question.
    • A computerised count of and IRV election would also take much more time to process than an Approval Voting election.
    • How many people still use Commodore 64 computers?
I realise you're just trying to make a concrete example here, but I think talking about Commodores and Pentiums is a bit completely off topic, and for that matter, underestimating the power of the Commodore 64 (and or paper/pencil). -- Kowey 09:26, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
Put simply, IRV requires several orders of magnitude greater computer power to process an election than FPTP, AppV, CumV, LimV. These less demanding systems only have to process each ballot once, can total things as they go, do not need to record a copy of any ballot (except for auditing purposes), and the software would be small and simple.
IRV is the opposite. However IRV computers do exist, and large enough computers also exist. IRV can still be done on paper ballots.
Syd1435 10:56, 2004 Oct 16 (UTC)
I think your orders of magnitude come from a poor choice of algorithm. The number of ballots in IRV is irrelvant; you only need to store M^2 numbers: for each candidate, the number of 1st rank votes, 2nd rank votes, etc. In other words, IRV is simpler to implement than you suggest, so be happy, but all this talk of complexity is not relevant to article on voting systems. -- Kowey 11:20, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
I am trying to concede that IRV requires more resources than other systems, and if these resources are not available, then a system like AppV would be a satisfactory second preference. If you are not bothered, fine. :-)
BTW, information must be stored for each of the N ballots, because with IRV, unlike FPTP or AppV, you cannot just add up the numbers on the ballot papers as they go by. These ballots must be reprocessed as many as M-1 times to attain a result.
Fine, my mistake; i hadn't understood how the IRV transfer worked and after rereading carefully, I will tentatively agree that you will need to store each ballot. But no, I am not bothered, and concession is not neccesary because I think it's not really pertinent to the article. -- Kowey 13:13, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)

Disadvanges with CAV sample ballot

The Citizens for Approval Voting website uses the following ballot paper as its logo:

    • [YES] Jefferson - a great president
    • [NO ] Stalin - a tyrant
    • [YES] Madison - a great president
    • [YES] Washington - a great president

Clearly, it does not matter which of these three great presidents wins, so long as Stalin loses.

But suppose the ballot was revised as follows:

    • [YES] Jefferson - a great president
    • [NO ] Stalin - a tyrant
    • [YES] Madison - a great president
    • [ ? ] Warren G. Harding - a ROTTEN president

Now the choice is less clear. We would want even Warren G. Harding to beat Stalin, but either Jefferson or Madison to beat Harding. This example shows a fundimental weakness of Approval Voting. Cumulative Voting does better, and Instant Runoff Voting better still.

Uh no? If fewer people like Harding, fewer people vote for him. Jefferson/Madison still win. Problem solved? -- Kowey 09:26, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)
Kowey overlooks the point that only Harding is contempory with Stalin, the other two presidents being dead. And what if the choice is between the worst three presidential candidates, say Harding, Dukakis and say Hoover?? -- Syd1435 20:26, 16 Oct 2004 (AEST)
    • [ ? ] Dukakis - an unsuccessful presidential candidate
    • [NO ] Stalin - a tyrant - was very "good" at being a tyrant.
    • [YES] Hoover - a unsuccessful president ?? excellent mining engineer in Australia and elsewhere.
    • [ ? ] Warren G. Harding - a ROTTEN president
Ok, here i'm confused: what does Harding's being contempory with Stalin have to do with anything? We're talking voting systems here with a hypothetical example, and for some reason or another the voter is presented with 4 choices. Easy enough, the voter selects his two acceptable choices. I also do not see how the case of four undesirable candidates (of which one or two really not desirable) is any different. You just pick the lesser evil(s)... or you file a protest vote by voting blank. -- Kowey 10:51, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)

Some additional points:

  • Approval voting is better than First Past the Post. FPTP is like a car with no gears. No Gears = Very Low Performance.
  • Approval voting is simple and inexpensive to implement, like a car with manual gears. Some performance.
  • Instant Runoff Voting is complicated and requires more resources, like a car with automatic gears. High Performance.
  • But IRV has been shown to work, in the same way that automatic gears for cars have been shown to work, and is worth doing.

-- Syd1435 20:26, 16 Oct 2004 (AEST)

Sure, I'll agree that AV and IRV are preferable to FPTP. But I suspect that you are over-estimating the gains from IRV (i.e. ability to rank your preferences) because you are not considering that these gains are offset by increasing the likelihood of strategic voting. In other words, AV's simplicity is an inherent virtue, not just an implementation advantage; it is, in a sense, more fool-resistant. But this is an opinion only; i don't have the real world examples to back this up. The CAV have a page that mentions this re-emergence of Wasted Vote Syndrome. They claim that this leads to strategic voting in practice (i.e. in Australia), exactly what I want to avoid.
That being said, the point here is not to convince the reader that we should use one system or another. We are an encyclopedia. The task at hand is help the user learn about the systems, how they work and what the basic implications are; it is not to sell them anything. -- Kowey 10:51, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)


Put simply, Approval Voting cannot simultaneously approve of multiple candidates and choose between them.

An even more telling ballot would be to place Stalin against the three worst presidents.

Strategic or Tactical Voting

Strategic or Tactical Voting occurs when a voter judges that their preferred candidate is not likely to win, and that therefore they are better off voting for a lesser of two evils candidate.

With FPTP, this can occur with three cornered contests. An unexpected third candiate can drain away enough votes to spoil victory for one of the leaders.

With Approval Voting, the drainage of votes is certain to be much less, since a voter can select both the original choice, as well as the lesser of two evils choice.

If however, the vote judges than their preferred candidate has a winning chance, they may decline to approve of the lesser of two evils choice, making room for the worst of two evils to get in, if they miscalculate. This could be gut-wrenching. Some voters will thus only approve of the preferred candidate and decline to support the lesser of two evils candidate, casting a FPTP like ballot.

With Instant Runoff Voting, the voter ranks their first choice first, the lesser of two evils candidate second, and the worst of all evils last. No combination or permutation of preferences can help elect the worst of all evils, assuming that the voter ranks all candidates. The need not be any leakage of preference that might spoil the result as a PFTP vote can do, or a AppV vote does to some extend.

When an IRV ballot is filled in, with all the candidates ranked consequtively from 1 to N, there can be no circular preferences, (A>B, B>C, C>A). Preferences always flow unambiguously D>A>E>B>C, etc.

With AppV ballot there are no circular rankings, but there are ambiguous rankings say (A=D=E)>(B=C).

With FPTP ballot, there are no circular rankings because say D>(A=B=C=E).

What is this ranking circularity called - Concordat blah blah???

Syd1435 11:48, 2004 Oct 16 (UTC)

Instant Runoff Equivalent of Approval Voting

Approval Voting can be converted into a form of Instant Runoff Voting by replacing YES with "1" and NO with "2"


  • [2] Joe Smith ----- Greens.
  • [1] Henry Ford ---- Rural Republican
  • [2] Jane Doe ------ Democrat
  • [2] Fred Rubble --- Reform
  • [1] Mary Hill ----- City Republican

Note how the numbers "1" and "2" are repeated.

If a voter desires to preference Ford ahead of Hill, while supporting both these Republicans against all others, then that voter would need to use the numbers "1", "2" and "3".

This "1" = "FULL YES", "2" = "PART YES", "3" = "NO"


  • [3] Joe Smith ----- Greens.
  • [1] Henry Ford ---- Rural Republican
  • [3] Jane Doe ------ Democrat
  • [3] Fred Rubble --- Reform
  • [2] Mary Hill ----- City Republican

It would not be Rocket Science to devise a (computerised) system to allow a voter to use either Approval Voting or Instant Runoff Voting in the same election.


  • [3] Joe Smith ----- Greens.
  • [1] Henry Ford ---- Rural Republican
  • [4] Jane Doe ------ Democrat
  • [5] Fred Rubble --- Reform
  • [2] Mary Hill ----- City Republican

A convential Instant Runoff Voting requires each square to be filled in by different consequtive numbers, which helps the electoral officials check for errors.

I don't see how this is relevant to the article, or to one about IRV. -- Kowey 09:36, 16 Oct 2004 (UTC)

Multiple winners

Approval voting can be extended to multiple winner elections, either as block approval voting, a simple variant on block voting where each voter can select an unlimited number of candidates and the candidates with the most approval votes win, or as proportional approval voting which seeks to maximise the overall satisfaction with the final result using approval voting.

A disadvantage of multiple winner voting, is that if there are N vacancies, voters must vote for N candidates, which is like N First Past the Post votes in parallel. The result if often a clean sweep by one major party or the other.

Limited Voting allows each voter M votes for N vacancies, where M < N, which reduces the likely of a clean sweep.

Cumulative Voting allows each voter M votes for N vacancies, where M <= N, but the voter can allocate those votes 1 each for M candidates or M votes for just 1 candidate, or something in between.


AV is an abbreviation of "Alternate Vote aka IRV" as well as Approval Voting. Can something be done to disambiguate this, by say calling Approval Voting AppV?

Syd1435 10:56, 2004 Oct 16 (UTC)